The federal government in the "Restoring American Financial Stability Act of 2010" reversed its long-standing policy of favoring disadvantaged borrowers. Under the new rules, borrowers who can qualify only for mortgages with relatively liberal repayment provisions, which are already priced higher because they are riskier to lenders, will be subject to an indirect cost that will affect only them.

The federal government in the "Restoring American Financial Stability Act of 2010" reversed its long-standing policy of favoring disadvantaged borrowers. Under the new rules, borrowers who can qualify only for mortgages with relatively liberal repayment provisions, which are already priced higher because they are riskier to lenders, will be subject to an indirect cost that will affect only them.

This unintended effect arises from new restrictions imposed on mortgage lenders, combined with a "safe harbor" where lenders are not subject to the restrictions.

Lenders are in the safe harbor when they make "qualified" mortgages, which are those with low-risk characteristics, such as fully amortizing payments, terms no longer than 30 years, qualification based on the highest possible rate in the first five years, and so on. Disadvantaged borrowers who need lower payments in the earlier years will require nonqualified mortgages.

The new burdens imposed on lenders are nontrivial. One holds lenders responsible for loans being "affordable," and spells out in excruciating detail all the bases lenders much touch in meeting this responsibility. A second burden is that lenders must retain at least 5 percent of the credit risk on new loans. But if a mortgage is qualified, the law presumes that it is affordable, and the lender is not obliged to retain any of the risk of loss.

Very shortly, the market will split between qualified and nonqualified mortgages. At best, the price difference between them will increase to reflect the new costs associated with nonqualified mortgages.

As an example, on July 19, the rates on 40-year fixed-rate mortgages were almost 1 percent higher than the rates on comparable 30-year mortgages. Because, under the Act, 40-year loans cannot be qualified, the price difference will widen as soon as lenders making 40-year loans are forced to assume the new burdens imposed by the Act. The borrower who needs a 40-year loan to qualify will be further disadvantaged.

At worst, the market for nonqualified mortgages will disappear altogether, or (almost as bad) will shift entirely to a small number of mega-lenders.

It would be one thing if crippling an important segment of the market — one that caters primarily to the disadvantaged — was a necessary price to pay for making the system safe and stable. It is quite another when the restrictions are not only unnecessary for achieving that objective, but will make the current excessive stringency in the home loan market even worse.

The rule that lenders should be responsible for all mortgage loans being affordable to the borrower is a knee-jerk reaction to the excesses of the bubble period, when many adjustable-rate loans to subprime borrowers were not affordable past the initial rate period — usually two years. The underlying presumption was that the lender would be protected by rising home values.

The fallacy of that presumption became so glaringly evident after the crisis that underwriting requirements — the rules defining who can and who cannot be approved — swung 180 degrees, from lady bountiful to Mr. Scrooge.

Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, whose excessive liberality during the bubble sowed the seeds of their subsequent insolvency, have been spearheading the swing to excessively restrictive rules. These are currently preventing millions of borrowers with perfect mortgage-payment records from being able to refinance at the currently low interest rates.

The current rules are as restrictive regarding affordability as those in the act, but they are not yet frozen into law.

A rigid affordability rule terminates an industry trend toward increasing flexibility in underwriting requirements. Over several decades ending in 2007, the industry (including Fannie and Freddie) learned that it was safe, fair and market-enlarging to balance one underwriting rule against another. Conventional ratios of housing expense to income became a part of the decision process but were no longer rigid barriers to approval.

As an example, before the crisis a borrower with a credit score of 800 and equity of 40 percent would be approved, even though he could not document much or any income. The sensible presumption was that such a borrower knew more about what he could afford than the underwriter, and in the unlikely case where the presumption was wrong, the lender was protected by the equity.

Today, such borrowers are being rejected out of hand. The Act would freeze this into law, since it explicitly bars lenders from basing a loan decision on the borrower’s equity.

This is absurd, not only because such loans are safe to the lender, but also because some unaffordable loans are clearly in the interest of borrowers. My website article, "Mortgage Affordability: Should Government Require It?" cites many different situations where a loan is both safe to the lender and useful to a borrower who can’t meet affordability tests.

Some of these involve using home equity to offset a temporary loss of income, much as in the case of reverse mortgages. The difference is that reverse mortgages are exempt from the affordability rules in the Act while other mortgages that employ the same principle of using equity to supplement income are not.

The second burden imposed on lenders by the Act, which they can escape only by writing qualified mortgages, is the 5 percent "skin in the game" requirement. It is an excellent rule to impose on issuers of mortgage-backed securities — if it had been in force during the bubble period, the panic would have been avoided.

Lenders made unaffordable loans during that period only because they could sell them to security issuers, who were able to shift the risk to investors. If security issuers had been on the hook for losses, none of it would have happened.

To protect the system, we need security issuers to have skin in the game. But imposing the rule on lenders accomplishes nothing except raising the cost of mortgages to disadvantaged borrowers.

Show Comments Hide Comments
Sign up for Inman’s Morning Headlines
What you need to know to start your day with all the latest industry developments
By submitting your email address, you agree to receive marketing emails from Inman.
Success!
Thank you for subscribing to Morning Headlines.
Back to top
×
Log in
If you created your account with Google or Facebook
Don't have an account?
Forgot your password?
No Problem

Simply enter the email address you used to create your account and click "Reset Password". You will receive additional instructions via email.

Forgot your username? If so please contact customer support at (510) 658-9252

Password Reset Confirmation

Password Reset Instructions have been sent to

Subscribe to The Weekender
Get the week's leading headlines delivered straight to your inbox.
Top headlines from around the real estate industry. Breaking news as it happens.
15 stories covering tech, special reports, video and opinion.
Unique features from hacker profiles to portal watch and video interviews.
Unique features from hacker profiles to portal watch and video interviews.
It looks like you’re already a Select Member!
To subscribe to exclusive newsletters, visit your email preferences in the account settings.
Up-to-the-minute news and interviews in your inbox, ticket discounts for Inman events and more
1-Step CheckoutPay with a credit card
By continuing, you agree to Inman’s Terms of Use and Privacy Policy.

You will be charged . Your subscription will automatically renew for on . For more details on our payment terms and how to cancel, click here.

Interested in a group subscription?
Finish setting up your subscription
×